Fishmeal has been used in pig and poultry feeds for several decades, and there is evidence of a kinked demand curve for fishmeal prior to aquaculture's entrance into this market (Hansen, 1980).
Consequently, we can hypothesize that there is a kinked demand curve for fishmeal.
This paper is concerned with the lower portion of the demand curve, below the kink of the famous
kinked demand curve model (Sweezy; Hall, and Hitch, 1939).
This type of
kinked demand curve would result in a relatively small price increase being profitable, when a larger price increase would not be.
This has resulted in a
kinked demand curve model for the market (please see Figure 1).
This suggests that a modified form of
kinked demand curve model may be more appropriate for modeling small business than typical Bertrand models, since Bertrand conjectures are symmetric with respect to increases or decreases in price.
This results in a classically kinked demand curve, as seen in Diagrams i and 2, given by DaDc.
So in Diagrams 1 and 2, we now have a kinked demand curve DaDc, with an adult portion above Wa, and a child portion below Wa.
In this paper, we examine whether retail grocery price-setters' reactions to competitive price changes are consistent with the "follow price cuts, don't follow price increases" reaction pattern assumed in the classic kinked demand curve theory (KDC) (cf.
The Kinked Demand Curve Theory: Follow Down, Not Up (FDNU)
(b) Likewise, from the vantage point of a small number of imperfect competitors, a concave to the origin,
kinked demand curve is incompatible with a constant elasticity.
For example, Dranove and Satterthwaite link a
kinked demand curve and balanced billing practice to provide a technical explanation of the effect of implementing a RBRVS on demand by Medicare patients.